Cato Policy Analysis No. 241 |
September 26, 1995 |
by James Bovard
James Bovard is an associate policy
analyst with the Cato Institute. His most recent book is Shakedown: How the
Government Screws You from A to Z (Viking, 1995).
Executive Summary
The Archer Daniels Midland Corporation (ADM) has been the most prominent recipient
of corporate welfare in recent U.S. history. ADM and its chairman Dwayne
Andreas have lavishly fertilized both political parties with millions of
dollars in handouts and in return have reaped billion-dollar windfalls from
taxpayers and consumers. Thanks to federal protection of the domestic sugar
industry, ethanol subsidies, and various other programs, ADM has cost the
American economy billions of dollars since 1980 and has indirectly cost
Americans tens of billions of dollars in higher prices and higher taxes over
that same period. At least 43 percent of ADM's annual profits are from products
heavily subsidized or protected by the American government. Moreover, every $1
of profits earned by ADM's corn sweetener operation costs consumers $10, and
every $1 of profits earned by its ethanol operation costs taxpayers $30
One of the most politically charged debates in Washington revolves around
business subsidies known as "corporate welfare." A number of policy
organizations have published studies examining the corporate welfare
phenomenon: what qualifies as corporate welfare, how much it costs taxpayers,
and how much it damages the economy. This study examines the dynamics of
corporate welfare somewhat differently by investigating ADM as a classic case
study of how those subsidies are obtained, how the welfare state encourages
such "rent seeking," and how such practices fundamentally corrupt the
political life of a nation. Congress's expressed desire to foster a free marketplace
cannot be taken seriously until ADM's corporate hand is removed from the
federal till.
Introduction
ADM is certainly the nation's most arrogant welfare recipient. And it is one
of the few welfare recipients that spend millions of dollars each year
advertising on Sunday morning television shows populated and watched by
politicians. Chairman Dwayne Andreas's and ADM's success in farming Washington
represents the rational result of contemporary government policies that turn
elections into "an advanced auction of stolen goods," as H. L.
Mencken quipped. Thanks to its multi-million-dollar hustling in Washington, a
company that lives and dies on the generosity of the American taxpayer has
managed to get itself revered as a great public servant. Although ADM is not the
only corporation with its hand out in Washington, it is easily one of the most
successful beggars on the block.(1)
Andreas recently told a reporter for Mother Jones, "There isn't one
grain of anything in the world that is sold in a free market. Not one! The only
place you see a free market is in the speeches of politicians. People who are
not in the Midwest do not understand that this is a socialist country."(2)
Andreas's comment about "no free markets" is like the old joke about
the son who murdered his parents and then asked for the court's mercy because
he was an orphan. ADM champions political control over markets and then invokes
that control as an excuse for its continued political manipulation. Andreas has
exerted his influence in Washington to ensure that the U.S. form of
"socialism" resembles 1930s' Italian corporate statism: the
government plunders the citizenry for the benefit of politically connected
corporations. And, though Andreas does not like to admit it, there are many
markets in the world for agricultural products that are not controlled by
politicians.
This past May ADM ran in major newspapers a full-page, full-color ad showing
a corn cob decorated with the American flag with a picture of President John F.
Kennedy along with Kennedy's most famous slogan, "Ask not what your
country can do for you--ask what you can do for your country." The
advertisement is the ultimate Orwellian agit-prop exercise, the true message
being, "Ask not what your country can do for you, ask what you can do for ADM."
Such misleading "public service" ad campaigns are the staple of ADM's
public relations operation, providing the thin cover necessary to plunder the
public till.
Although much has been written lately on ADM and its harvest of taxpayer
dollars, the full scope of its parasitic relationship with the U.S. taxpayer
has rarely been closely examined. This study provides that detailed examination
as well as an insight into the political dynamics that encourage corporate
leaders to profit, not by pleasing consumers, but by pleasing politicians. The
study also examines the three main arenas for ADM's corporate rent seeking: the
ethanol program, the sugar program, and subsidized grain exports.
Tithing at the Church of
Subsidy
Andreas has long talked and behaved as if he had a divine mission to give as
much money as possible to as many politicians as possible. The Washington Post
noted in 1985 that "Andreas said he was raised in a religious tradition
that called for 'tithing' 10 percent of personal income to the church. And, he
adds, 'I consider politics to be just like the church.'"(3) Andreas
likewise declared in 1990, "I was raised to believe you're supposed to
support your mayor and your congressman and your politicians. . . . If a fellow
is willing to devote his life to public service, and a fellow like me has more
money than I ever dreamed existed in the whole world, wouldn't I be an ass if I
didn't respond to requests?"(4) One should not be surprise that the
"public services" that Andreas rewards are services that subsidize
ADM.
The Wall Street Journal declared on July 11 that "for more than two
decades, Mr. Andreas has reigned as the prince of political influence."(5)
The Washington Post described Andreas as "one of the great financial
'switch hitters' of American politics," meaning that ADM will bankroll any
politician who supports ethanol or sugar subsidies regardless of political
creed or ideological convictions.(6) Andreas has done a masterful job of
diversifying his investments by carefully cultivating both Senate Majority
Leader Bob Dole and Senate Minority Leader Tom Daschle. The New York Times in
1990 called Dole "ADM's staunchest ally on Capitol Hill."(7) The Wall
Street Journal likewise recently reported, "In the Senate, Mr. Dole has been
the chief promoter of the ethanol subsidy."(8) The Times also noted that
"ADM's private plane has flown Dole to Midwest speaking engagements, and
for a time ADM sponsored Dole's commentaries over the Mutual Radio Network. The
Senator and his wife, Elizabeth Dole, then Secretary of Labor, purchased an
apartment from Andreas in 1982 at the Sea View, a Bal Harbour, Florida, hotel
in which residents hold shares. They paid $150,000--less than the apartment's
market value."(9) Since 1993 Dole has accepted 29 flights on ADM's private
planes (Dole reimburses the company for the price of a first-class ticket--far
less than the cost of chartering a private plane).(10) After Elizabeth Dole
became the head of the Red Cross, Andreas's nonprofit foundation gave $1
million to the Red Cross. Andreas also donated $100,000 to Bob Dole's now
defunct Better America Foundation.
Since 1979 Andreas, family members, and ADM have contributed more than $4
million to congressional and presidential candidates, as well as to the
national Democratic and Republican parties.(11)
In the two years before the 1992 election, ADM gave $772,000 to Republicans
but only $136,500 to Democrats.(12) But the likelihood of Clinton's victory did
wonders for Andreas's bipartisan spirit. According to the Wall Street Journal,
"Andreas, whose personal contributions heavily favored Republican
candidates in 1992, weighed in a mere six days before the presidential election
with a $50,000 contribution to the Democrats' congressional campaign
committee."(13)
Frank Greven of Knight-Ridder News Service noted earlier this year that, in
the 1992 presidential race, "Andreas and his family and his companies gave
a combined total of nearly $1.4 million to Democratic and Republican party
efforts on behalf of Clinton and Bush. Among Democratic party givers, Andreas
and company ranked third, according to a tabulation by the Center for
Responsive Politics. Among Republican party givers, they ranked first.
Andreas-related contributions to individual candidates were also split in
November's mid-term elections: $461,500 to Democrats, $325,268 to Republicans.
Hundreds of thousands of dollars more, like the Red Cross contribution, have
flowed from the Andreas Foundation or the ADM Foundation to charitable causes
championed by key lawmakers like Dole."(14) Andreas is even a dedicated
caretaker of the image of dead politicians: he donated $1 million--the largest
donation received so far--to the Richard Nixon Center for Peace and Freedom.
As the Charlotte Observer's Frank Greven notes, Andreas has also been
generous to House Speaker Newt Gingrich. "Andreas' large and pre-victory
contribution to Gingrich was a reported $70,000 to GOPAC, the nonprofit
organization used by Gingrich since 1987 to pay for airline travel, mail
videotapes and speeches and generally build national visibility for Republican
candidates."(15) Gingrich, responding to widespread criticism, distanced
himself from GOPAC in May.
Andreas donated $100,000 to a single Democratic fundraising dinner in
1994.(16) In the first 18 months of the Clinton administration, as Peter Stone
of the National Journal reported, Andreas and ADM donated over $300,000
"in soft money to Democratic groups--roughly six times what they contributed
to Republicans."(17)
Andreas has also reached into his pocket to help politicians in their
personal struggles. When Sen. Tom Harkin (D-Iowa) was sued for libel in 1986
because of a campaign statement, Andreas gave $10,000 to a legal defense fund
for Harkin and two aides.(18) When former president Jimmy Carter decided to get
out of the peanut business, Andreas was there with a check for $1.2 million to
help Carter promote Habitat for Humanity.(19)
Dwayne Andreas: Donor with a
Cause
Perhaps not surprisingly, Andreas's penchant for funding politicians has
repeatedly run him afoul of the law. Mother Jones, for example, has reported,
"In a recently released deposition, Richard Nixon's secretary, Rose Mary
Woods, recalled a 1972 personal visit from Andreas in which he delivered an
unmarked envelope containing $100,000 in $100 bills. The cash spent a year or
so in a White House safe before Nixon, with the Watergate investigation closing
in around him, decided to give it back."(20) The Los Angeles Times noted
last year that "a $25,000 [Andreas] campaign contribution in 1972 to Nixon
fundraiser Kenneth Dahlberg turned him into what he once described to the
Washington Post as an 'innocent bystander' in the Watergate scandal. That money
ended up in the bank account of Watergate burglar Bernard Barker, giving
investigators the first link between the Watergate break-in and the Nixon
campaign committee."(21) Of course, most "innocent bystanders"
do not offer $25,000 in cash to people who can do them big favors.
Senator and Vice President Hubert Humphrey was one of Andreas's first major
sweethearts in Washington. The Washington Post reported that "Andreas
introduced Humphrey to business leaders, paid for the military school education
of one of his children, and managed Humphrey's blind financial trust."(22)
Andreas was indicted by Watergate special prosecutor Archibald Cox for making
an illegal contribution of $100,000 to Humphrey's 1968 presidential campaign.
He was acquitted of that charge by a Minnesota jury.
Between 1975 and 1977 Andreas gave $72,000 in ADM stock to the children of
David Gartner, then-senator Humphrey's chief of staff. After President Carter
named Gartner to the Commodity Futures Trading Commission in 1977, news of the
ADM windfall leaked out. Because ADM, like other major agricultural and grain
corporations, is heavily involved in commodity futures trading, the handouts
raised red flags throughout Washington. Vice President Walter Mondale took the
lead in pressuring Gartner to resign "on the grounds that the ethical
appearances surrounding that matter were such that he could not operate without
public questioning of his integrity and the independence of his
judgment."(23) Gartner, however, refused to budge.(24)
More recently, Andreas and his wife, Dorothy, paid an $8,000 fine to the
Federal Election Commission in 1993 for exceeding legal limits of $25,000 a
year in contributions to political candidates.(25)
One amusing aspect of Andreas's bipartisan bankrolling is that both parties
realize he has no specific loyalty to them, but as long as he and his cohorts
are willing to write checks for millions, members of Congress and presidents
are happy to perpetuate billions in handouts for ADM. Regardless of how much
such a deal costs American taxpayers and consumers, it is still profitable for
politicians. ADM's success highlights the absurdity of the interventionist
state in which imaginative and highly skilled political businessmen can get
hundredfold returns on their handouts to politicians.
Although Andreas has pulled all the strings to ensure that ADM's own gravy
train continues, he is at least patriotic enough to believe that Congress and
the president must act to end the federal deficit. On January 26, 1993, six
days after Bill Clinton had taken the oath of office, Andreas bravely called
for shock therapy and $150 billion in new taxes. "I think it's time for
Americans to face up to the fact that we have to accept the taxes that will
keep our country solid and preserve our democracy."(26) Fiscal sacrifices,
apparently, must be made by the taxpayers but not by the recipients of taxpayer
largesse.
The basic problem here is, not that businessmen occasionally give large sums
of money to politicians, but that what they are trying to "buy" ought
not to be for sale in the first place. Mencken's "advanced auction of
stolen goods" has two guilty parties, the auctioneers and the bidders. And
it is the auction--not the existence of wealthy bidders--that cries out for
attention.
Ethanol: The Great Agricultural "White Hope"
Nothing symbolizes ADM's political exploitation of Americans better than
ethanol. Ethanol has become a magic obeisance button for politicians. Simply
mention the word and politicians grovel like trained dogs, competing to heap
the most praise on ethanol and its well-connected producers. Regardless of how
uncompetitive the product may be, politicians have for years talked about
ethanol as if it were the agricultural equivalent of holy water. Ethanol
producers have received a de facto subsidy of nearly $10 billion since
1980--yet they continue demanding more, more, more.
Andreas has long sought to frame the ethanol issue in histrionic terms.
Burning tax dollars to artificially jam ears of corn into gas tanks seems to
have near-cosmic significance. In 1988 Andreas hailed ADM's ethanol operations
as "a service to corn growers" and "a service to
humanity."(27) Andreas declared in 1992, "This is the Midwest vs. the
Middle East. It's corn farmers vs. the oil companies."(28) Ethanol
producers view themselves, not as self- serving corporations at the federal
trough, but as veritable Mother Theresas striving to save the world with clean
air and renewable resources.
Ethanol is produced by distilling corn into alcohol. Ethanol is simply grain
alcohol--"white lightning"--the same substance used to fortify MD
20/20 or gin. Ethanol can be mixed--one part ethanol to nine parts gasoline--to
make gasohol. Tom Donlan, editorial page editor of Barron's, observed last year
that the ethanol controversy is simply one more episode in the dispute over
corn whiskey that has been going on since the birth of the American Republic:
"200 proof corn liquor is still the same stuff for which western
Pennsylvania farmers fought the Whiskey Rebellion of 1792. In this more
complicated age, a new Whiskey Rebellion must be fought by aggrieved
taxpayers" against wasteful ethanol subsidies.(29)
Although proponents of ethanol argue that such fuel is better for the
environment and helps reduce America's reliance on foreign oil (while not at
all incidentally providing a new market for corn farmers), the fuel itself is
inferior to straight gasoline and the collateral benefits promised by
supporters are fewer than meet the eye.
Ethanol 101
Ethanol producers receive an array of subsidies from federal and state governments.
The largest subsidy is the exemption from federal fuel taxes. Gasoline
companies receive a tax break of 5.4 cents for each gallon of gasohol they
sell. Because gasohol is usually sold in a mixture of nine parts gasoline to
one part ethanol, each gallon of ethanol receives the equivalent of a 54 cent
break from the federal tax code. While it is often misleading to speak of tax
deductions and credits as the equivalent of a direct federal subsidy, it is
certainly the case that, without the massive distortion of the tax code, there
would be no ethanol industry, given the large cost differential in the
production of ethanol and traditional gasoline.
Ethanol subsidies reduce federal revenues by $770 million a year,(30) losses
that the Congressional Research Service estimates could rise to $1 billion by
the year 2000.(31) Many state governments also heavily subsidize the production
or use of ethanol.(32)
Federal policy is not designed to simply "level the playing
field," or even to tilt the playing field in ethanol's favor. Instead, the
program amounts to nothing less than buying the entire playing field and giving
the title directly to ethanol producers. Ethanol, as far as it is used for
gasoline, is a political concoction--a product that exists and is used solely
because of the interference of politicians with the workings of the
marketplace. Ethanol producers must heavily bankroll politicians because their
product would otherwise vanish overnight from the nation's gas pumps.
As early as 1979 the Washington Post reported, "The gasohol lobby says
the $18.80 a barrel in available subsidies--compared with the $16 a barrel cost
for foreign oil-- is not enough."(33) The tax exemption or credit for
ethanol production has consistently exceeded the entire value of the gasoline
that ethanol displaces. The 54-cent-per-gallon tax deduction or credit is the
equivalent of a subsidy of $23 per barrel of oil displaced at a time when oil
costs only about $18 a barrel.(34)
In 1986 the U.S. Department of Agriculture estimated the average cost of
producing ethanol at $l.60 a gallon, more than double the then wholesale
gasoline price of 60 cents a gallon (the current wholesale price is roughly 55
cents).
The ethanol debate is unlike the typical economic argument for an infant industry
to which the government provides small subsidies or trade protection for a
short period to help the new industry get on its feet. Instead, a perpetual,
massive subsidy has been maintained in order to keep an existing industry from
sinking under the weight of its own helpless uncompetitiveness. Rather than an
infant industry, ethanol is an industry that, in economic terms, was born
senile and has since gotten fat.
Ethanol has done poorly on its own largely because it is a relatively lousy
fuel. An Agriculture Department report observed,
Each gallon of ethanol contains
about two-thirds as much energy as does gasoline, resulting in reduced fuel
economy. One would expect vehicles using gasohol to show about a 3.3 percent
reduction in miles per gallon since ethanol constitutes 10 percent of the
ethanol-gasoline blend. In a recent report on the performance of
alcohol-gasoine blends, the DOE concluded that gasohol-fueled vehicles averaged
4.7 percent fewer miles per gallon than gasoline-fueled vehicles in automobile
fleets.(35)
The comparatively feeble fuel value of ethanol is a large part of the reason
why the fuel is so discounted from its cost of production. The USDA report
further noted,
Fuel ethanol sold for about $0.90
per gallon in July 1986. This price does not reflect its free market value
because gasoline blenders qualify for Federal and State ethanol subsidies.
After deducting the value of the subsidies ($0.60 per gallon for the Federal
subsidy and some $0.30- $0.40 average for State subsidies) the net cost of
ethanol to blenders is about zero. This indicates that ethanol producers could
not survive without the subsidies, and suggests that most will need even larger
subsidies to stay in business unless petroleum prices increase sharply. Net of
applicable subsidies, ethanol is selling for about $0.30 per gallon less than
the wholesale price of gasoline.(36)
Yet, while ethanol was selling (net of subsidies) for half the price of
gasoline, it cost more than twice as much to produce as gasoline. Obviously,
government intervention is necessary.
The Politics of Ethanol
Ethanol has long been the "great white hope" of the farm lobby.
Since the era of the Civil War, farm lobbyists have called for government
subsidies to convert crop surpluses into fuels and thereby make the surpluses
disappear and drive up crop prices forever. However, the ploy has not worked
out very well. The Congressional Research Service, in an analysis of federal
subsidies and tax incentives for ethanol, concluded in an October 1994 report,
For four reasons, the alcohol
fuels tax incentives are economically less efficient than alternative energy
tax policies:
(1) They provide subsidies to
alcohol fuel producers when economic principles suggest that no subsidy, and
maybe even a tax, should be imposed;
(2) They fail to fully tax users
of alcohol fuels in transportation on a par with users of gasoline and
commensurate with the benefits received from the system of national highways;
(3) The tax component that
corrects for the negative environmental externalities from the combustion and
evaporation of alcohol of vehicles is the same as gasoline when theory and
evidence suggests that it be less than for gasoline;
(4) As a policy to stimulate
alternative fuels, targeting alcohol subsidizes more expensive fuel when
economic theory suggests that the market will determine the least expensive
fuels to use.(37)
The rationale for ethanol subsidies has continually changed to meet shifting
political winds. In the late 1970s ethanol was championed as a way to achieve
energy independence. In the early 1980s ethanol was portrayed as salvation for
struggling corn farmers. From the mid and late 1980s onward, ethanol has been
justified as saving the environment. However, none of those claims can
withstand serious examination.
Using ethanol for vehicle fuel is hardly a new practice. In fact, ethanol
has been used for fuel for more than 100 years. A USDA report noted, "The
use of alcohol as an automobile fuel dates back to the first modern internal
combustion engine, the Otto Cycle (1876), which used alcohol as well as
gasoline. Henry Ford designed the Model T (1908) to use alcohol, gasoline, or
any mixture of them."(38) State and federal governments have long striven
to rig the economic playing field to benefit ethanol producers.
By the early 1970s the use of ethanol for fuel had almost completely
disappeared in the United States. But, after President Nixon took the United
States off the gold standard and slashed the value of the dollar, the
Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries was formed and launched its brief
embargo of oil sales to the United States. Ethanol then found a new lease on
life, as midwestern states rushed to create tax incentives and loan programs
for ethanol production. In 1977 Congress passed an act directing the secretary
of agriculture to invest $60 million in guaranteed loans for ethanol
distilleries.
When OPEC restricted oil production again in 1978--and the Carter
administration tightened oil and gasoline rationing, creating artificial panic--Andreas
arrived at the White House with a salvation scheme. Why not increase subsidies
for ethanol? According to Frank Greven, who is working on a book on Andreas and
ADM, "During the 1978 Persian Gulf oil crisis, he convinced Carter that
using ADM's ethanol as a lead-free octane booster in gasoline would promote
energy independence and cleaner air."(39) As part of its grandiose
solution to the energy crisis--which the president proclaimed to be the moral
equivalent of war--the Carter administration drove through Congress a plan to
exempt gasoline with 10 percent ethanol from the 4-cents-a-gallon federal fuel
excise tax.
Even with the extremely generous federal tax credits for ethanol use, the
alternative fuel still did not take off. Politicians decided that massively
subsidizing ethanol's use was not sufficient; they must also massively
subsidize its production.
Not all were fooled by the near-religious tone of the pro-ethanol campaign
in the late 1970s. Syndicated columnist Jane Bryant Quinn observed at the time,
"The recipe for successful politics shows similar proportions: nine parts
of regional pandering, overlaid with one part national purpose. The explosive
mixture of excess corn in an election year ignited the gasohol program and will
keep it running." Quinn related widespread and accurate perceptions of the
defects of gasohol. "Vapor lock (boiling in the fuel pump) is more
prevalent with gasohol. It's more explosive than gasoline. The first time you
put it in your tank it might loosen some rust and clog some lines. The EPA says
that you'll get about 3 percent fewer miles per gallon with gasohol. If you
don't correct for the lower mileage by driving a more fuel-efficient car (or
driving less), you'll fritter away the oil savings by tanking up more often."(40)
On the eve of the 1980 election, the Carter administration announced a
deluge of loans to companies to build processing plants to make ethanol. On
October 9, 1980, Secretary of Agriculture Bob Bergland announced $341 million
in new loans to finance construction of gasohol plants.(41) On January 27,
1981, the new Reagan administration rescinded all the loans after its inspector
general discovered that the Carter administration had violated official
procedures and federal law in awarding many of the grants. Testimony by private
investigators at a congressional hearing in February 1981 revealed that some of
the loans were "reviewed in a matter of days, some in a matter of
hours." Bruce Yellen of the Chicago-based Better Government Association
told Congress, "Two loan guarantees were approved for individuals who had
contributed to the Democratic National Committee or the Carter campaign. And 10
of the 15 guarantees went to states that were, at the time, considered critical
to the president's re-election bid. These elements suggested that this
last-minute rush was politically inspired, and our interviews with agency
officials substantiated that point." He said that one official said that
an October 10 announcement of the guarantees was timed as "a public relations
ploy for political gain."(42)
Although the Reagan administration initially blocked the loans, the farm
lobby prevailed and the new administration added its seal of approval to
ethanol. Nevertheless, 9 of the 12 recipients of the loans the Farmers Home
Administration made for ethanol plants went bankrupt.
The Energy Department also got into the ethanol game and has lost more than
$100 million on recipients' defaults on ethanol loans. Andreas was less than
pleased at the prospect of more tax-subsidized competition. On August 20, 1981,
he wrote to James Stearns, then director of the Office of Alcohol Fuels at the
Department of Energy, to urge the government not to go through with loan
guarantees it had announced for 11 small ethanol producers. He noted, "It
is very clear to me that your program to finance totally inexperienced
individuals in their investments mostly as tax shelters is counterproductive in
that it has discouraged the flow of private capital into new
facilities."(43) Andreas went on to complain about Brazilian ethanol
imports in the same letter. At the time, ADM controlled over 70 percent of
ethanol production facilities in the United States.
Andreas's single largest rip-off of taxpayers occurred in 1986. The price of
corn had risen and the price of gasoline had fallen. Clearly, ethanol had
become a greater economic absurdity than ever. Andreas and ethanol supporters
had an easy solution: make ethanol pseudocompetitive again through USDA gifts
of free corn. Andreas and his top lobbyist met with USDA secretary Richard Lyng
for a breakfast at the Madison Hotel in Washington. Two days later Lyng
announced a new program under which ADM would receive $29 million in free corn
and other ethanol producers would receive multi-million-dollar corn windfalls.
The USDA's Office of Energy proposed targeting the free corn to only those
ethanol producers that were in severe financial distress. But Secretary Lyng
personally vetoed the "means test" idea as unfair. Lyng declared that
imposing a means test "didn't make sense to me at all. . . . I think the
government should treat people equally. . . . The Constitution calls for
that."(44) But, because only a handful of ethanol producers were eligible
for the multi-million-dollar giveaway, Lyng's profession of concern about
"equal treatment" was ludicrous, even by Washington standards. Jack
Blum, a lawyer for the Independent Gasoline Markets Council, denounced the
giveaway as "corporate food stamps for ADM."(45) One company, New
Energy Corporation, received almost $5 million worth of free corn and then went
bankrupt a few months later.
Ethanol: Beggar Thy Farmer Neighbor
Agriculture secretary Mike Espy hailed the Clinton administration's mandate
to force the use of ethanol in gas tanks. "One of my top priorities is improving
farm income, and this initiative will do just that."(46) Indeed, the USDA
currently estimates that each 100 million bushels of corn used for ethanol
production increase corn prices by between 4 and 8 cents. Hosein Shapouri, one
of the USDA's chief ethanol experts, estimated that the current level of 550
million bushels of corn used for ethanol production increases corn prices by
between 22 cents and 40 cents per bushel.(47) Advocates of farm aid claim that
the federal program--by boosting corn prices--boosts farm income by over a
billion dollars a year.
The primary effect of ethanol subsidies on agricultural markets, however, is
to allow corn farmers to charge hog farmers and cattlemen higher prices.
Roughly 60 percent of all the corn produced in the United States is used
domestically for feed grain. For example, the USDA estimates that 5.6 billion
bushels of the record 1994 corn crop will be used for that purpose.(48)
Assuming that ethanol inflates corn prices by 22 cents a bushel, ethanol
policies clearly cost cattle, pork, and other livestock producers more than a
billion dollars a year. That fits the historical pattern of farm policy:
intentionally sacrificing relatively unsubsidized farmers to subsidized farmers
and making all farm profits and losses increasingly a question of political
pull. The higher the price of feed grain, the higher the cost of meat
production. Thus, consumers get hit from all directions.
Perhaps the most honest and thorough analysis of the effect of ethanol on
farm income and taxpayers and consumers was done by the USDA's Office of Energy
in 1986. That study, which included a lower estimate of the inflationary impact
of ethanol production on corn prices, concluded,
Corn prices would increase by
$0.02-$0.04 per bushel for each 100 million bushel increase in ethanol-induced
demand for corn. However, soybean prices would fall by about $0.04 per bushel
and soybean prices would fall by $0.12-$0.15 per hundredweight.
Higher corn prices from
additional ethanol- induced demand would increase the cost of producing beef,
pork, and poultry. Consumer food expenditures would rise by $8.6 billion, or an
average of $2.29 for each additional gallon of ethanol produced.
When all the costs and benefits
are tallied, the Government, taxpayers and consumers together would lose
$6.1-$7.2 billion or $1.61-$1.92 per additional gallon produced during the
1986-94 period if ethanol subsidies were increased enough to prompt the ethanol
industry to produce 2 billion gallons in 1995. Conversely, if ethanol production
falls to zero, they would save some $6.8-$8.9 billion, or $1.35-$1.76 per
gallon not produced.(49)
The study concluded that increased production of ethanol would cost
consumers and taxpayers roughly $4 for each $1 of extra farm income. The report
stated,
Increases in consumer food
expenditures caused by additional ethanol production far exceed the increases
in farm income. Consumers would be much better off if they burned straight
gasoline in their automobiles and paid a direct cash subsidy to farmers in the
amount that net farm income would be increased by ethanol production.(50)
Since the USDA report came out, the amount of corn used for ethanol
production has increased by more than 300 million bushels a year. Going on the
report's assumptions, that means that soybean prices have been 12 cents a
bushel lower than they otherwise would have been--a loss of $300 million to
soybean farmers on their 1994 harvest of 2.5 billion bushels.(51)
A more recent USDA analysis, published in November 1993, concluded that
increased ethanol production would decrease soybean prices, boost variable
production costs for livestock by $462 million, and result in an overall loss
of $133 million for farmers outside the northern plains, the Corn Belt, and the
Great Lakes states.(52) The study concluded that federal mandates could boost
the amount of corn used to produce ethanol by 240 million bushels by 1997. But
the net increase in corn use would be only 154 million bushels because the
remainder of the corn used for ethanol will be corn that otherwise (if the
additional ethanol use had not boosted corn prices) would have gone to export
markets or been used as feed grain.(53)
Converting corn into fuel is not cheap. Fred Sanderson of Resources for the
Future notes, "It would be cheaper to dump the corn into the
ocean."(54) Even when corn is free, it is not possible to sell the ethanol
for a profit without massive tax subsidies.
Unfortunately, the more effective ethanol is in driving up the price of
corn, the less competitive both corn exports and ethanol become. Ethanol is
only viable with relatively cheap corn. The USDA estimates that corn farmers
will receive more than $3 billion in direct federal subsidies this year. Farm
aid advocates use two different arguments: one, that ethanol subsidies make the
cost of farm programs lower than they would otherwise be and, two, that corn
farmers deserve more help anyway. However, corn subsidies have been far higher
since ethanol came into vogue in the late 1970s than they were in the years
just before the promotion of ethanol became federal policy in 1978 (Table 1).
Total federal subsidies for corn production since 1978 exceed $67 billion.
Although farm-state politicians often claim that ethanol subsidies are an
excellent way to reduce other farm subsidy spending, the USDA concluded,
"Subsidies
Table 1 |
|
Year |
Cost |
1975 |
150 |
1976 |
112 |
1977 |
400 |
1978 |
1,697 |
1979 |
867 |
1980 |
1,256 |
1981 |
-667 |
1982 |
4,207 |
1883 |
5,720 |
1984 |
-934 |
1985 |
4,403 |
1986 |
10,524 |
1987 |
12,346 |
1988 |
8,227 |
1989 |
2,863 |
1990 |
2,435 |
1991 |
2,387 |
1992 |
2,105 |
1993 |
5,143 |
1994 |
972 |
1995 |
3,701 |
Sources: USDA, "Feed Grains: Background for 1995 Farm
Legislation," April 1995, appendix 4, p. 53; the value for 1994 and the
estimate for 1995 are from USDA, "Budget Summary, 1996," p. 30.
required to sustain the ethanol industry will offset any savings in
agricultural commodity programs resulting from the increased demand for
corn."(55) If Congress is truly concerned about reducing government
outlays on corn, it should simply abolish the corn program. That is the only
sure way to save billions of dollars a year--far more than the nickel-and-dime
savings alleged to result from the use of ethanol.
Ethanol and the Energy Security Chimera
In 1974 President Richard M. Nixon, responding to the Arab oil embargo,
announced a goal of "energy independence" for the United States by
1980. Nixon's proclamation sounded like those frequently made by leaders of
Third World nations that believe they can become rich by replacing imports at
any cost while totally neglecting the efficiency of everything else in the
national economy.
Much of the support for ethanol is based on a discredited mercantilist
perspective, which implicitly assumes that it is better to use American-made
products, regardless of the cost, instead of imported products, regardless of
the savings or benefits. The Congressional Budget Office, in a March 1995
report, noted,
Motor fuels blended with ethanol
made up less than 1 percent of the total motor fuels market in 1980, but that
proportion grew to nearly 7 percent by 1990. Because ethanol production uses
more resources than gasoline production, the resulting allocation of resources
may create economic inefficiencies if the value of those resources in
alternative uses is greater than the value of the diminution in air
pollution.(56)
Not only does ethanol cost roughly twice as much to produce as gasoline, but
producing ethanol may actually be a net destroyer of energy. The Oil & Gas
Journal reported in 1980 that production data from a 1979 application for a
federal ethanol subsidy filed by ADM with the Energy Department stated that
ADM's Decatur, Illinois, plant was producing 1,485 barrels of ethanol a day. At
that time, the plant was consuming the equivalent of 1,284 barrels of natural
gas to produce the ethanol, and the electricity used to power the plant was
equivalent to another 46 barrels of gas a day. Thus, looking only at the energy
used directly in ethanol production, analysts found that the plant showed a
"net energy gain" of only 165 barrels of ethanol a day--less than 15
percent of the total ethanol produced. But, as the Oil & Gas Journal noted,
"The ADM analysis presented to the Department of Energy, however, didn't
disclose the energy input associated with growing, harvesting, and transporting
the corn feedstock for the plant."(57)
Ethanol's drag on the energy supply continues to be a problem that few
ethanol advocates enjoy admitting. As the Washington Post noted last year,
Many farmers use gas guzzling tractors and other
energy-inefficient equipment that add to the total of air pollution and
greenhouse gases. . . . Moreover, in many older ethanol plants, it takes more
energy to make ethanol than the resulting product contains. In spite of ongoing
modifications, many ethanol factories are powered by coal, another heavy source
of greenhouse emissions. . . . Finally, the current method of manufacturing
ethanol centers on the extraction of sugars from corn for fermentation, as well
as the heating and cooling of the resulting liquid to distill alcohol. Both are
heavily energy-intensive processes.
As a result, the net energy efficiency of ethanol
is in question. One gallon of ethanol contains the energy equivalent of 76,000
British Thermal Units (BTUs). In 1991, the Department of Energy estimated that
to make a gallon of ethanol required 85,000 to 91,000 BTUs.(58)
Ethanol's Environmental Smoke and Mirrors
ADM officials stress ethanol's environmental benefits, but that is a very
different tune than was sung in the 1970s. In fact, the environmental problems
of ethanol have long been obvious. The Clean Air Act of 1977 actually banned
products such as ethanol. President Carter's EPA announced in 1978 that
"recent EPA and Department of Energy tests . . . show slight increases in
nitrogen oxide emissions and substantial increases in evaporate hydrocarbon
emissions" from cars using gasohol."(59) But because ethanol amounted
to only about 0.005 percent of the nation's gasoline sales, EPA administrator
Douglas Costle ruled that "there is no significant environmental risk
associated with its continued use."(60)
Since 1978 far more evidence has accumulated showing ethanol's harm to the
environment. As a 1986 USDA report noted, "Alcohol blends are significantly
more volatile than alcohol-free gasolines. Evaporative emissions reported for
ethanol blends are 5 percent to 220 percent above emissions for straight
gasoline."(61) A May 1990 study by former California Air Resources Board
chief Thomas C. Austin concluded that the standard gasohol mixture of 90
percent gasoline to 10 percent ethanol "could cut carbon-monoxide
emissions by 25 percent but that hydrocarbons would rise by as much as 50
percent and nitrogen oxide by 15 percent. Moreover, because gasohol gets a 6
cents per gallon subsidy (or 60 cents per gallon for pure ethanol),
ethanol-using motorists end up paying more for dirtier air."(62) The
National Academy of Sciences likewise concluded that "using ethanol as a
blending agent in gasoline . . . would not achieve significant air-quality
benefits and, in fact, would likely be detrimental."(63)
Federal agencies have also concluded that ethanol's environmental benefits,
at least in terms of smog reduction, are either a mirage or a yet unproven wish.
Regardless, senators like Bob Dole have sought to attach provisions
benefiting ethanol to many unrelated bills. The 1990 amendments to the Clean
Air Act provided ethanol with one of its biggest windfalls ever. The act
required motorists in the cities with the worst air quality to use gasoline
with at least 2 percent oxygen. Many other cities voluntarily chose to use the
reformulated gasoline.
When EPA proposed its initial implementing regulations for the Clean Air Act
in March 1992, the standard for gasoline volatility would have effectively
blocked the use of ethanol during the summer in the nation's most polluted
cities.(67) However, the forces of farm evangelism and ADM- financed
politicians soon jumped on the decision. As President Bush's reelection
prospects worsened, ethanol's prospects brightened. On October 1, 1992, Bush
announced plans to partially waive the volatility requirement to allow ethanol
to be used even though it could cause more pollution.(68) Bush's announcement
was jeered by environmentalists and others as a cynical ploy that sacrificed
the environment to his political needs. After Bush's defeat, his proposal was
effectively off the table.
Under the 1990 Clean Air Act, rather than an agency's issuing rules
unilaterally, the major players were invited to negotiate what the rules would
be in what is known inside the Beltway as a regulatory negotiation, or
"RegNeg." As Chemical & Engineering News noted in 1992,
This regulatory negotiation
approach was unprecedented in EPA's rulemaking process. Among others,
representatives of the ethanol, oil, methanol, and auto industries and from the
states were on the negotiating committee. All had their own ax to grind.
EPA and every member of the
committee signed "an agreement in principle" in August 1991. EPA
filed a supplemental notice of proposed rulemaking in April 1992, outlining the
regulations that would govern the reformulated gasoline program. The negotiated
agreement was the foundation for those proposed regulations.(69)
Ethanol was not mandated for use in gasoline largely because of the
environmental problems that ethanol causes.
Although ethanol supporters signed the agreement, they quickly effectively
reneged on the RegNeg. Ethanol advocates claimed that they had not understood
that the agreement they signed would effectively prevent the use of ethanol in
the summer in some of the nation's largest and most polluted cities. EPA
unilaterally issued a waiver to permit the use of more volatile fuel additives.
As Chemical & Engineering News noted,
Increased volatility poses a
problem of more organic chemicals finding their way into the atmosphere.
Blending 10 percent ethanol into gasoline, the usual ratio in gasohol,
increases volatility of gasoline by 1 psi, as measured by Reid Vapor Pressure
(RVP). The higher the RVP number, the more volatile the fuel. So despite how
critical a volatility waiver is for ethanol, nowhere was ethanol specifically
granted a 1-psi waiver from reformulated gasoline's volatility
standards."(70)
On June 30, 1994, Clinton announced that the EPA would ignore the protests
and impose its ethanol mandate on the nation's gasoline pumps. Clinton
justified the ethanol mandate by declaring that it would provide
"thousands of new jobs for the future" and that "this policy is
good for our environment, our public health, and our nation's farmers-- and
that's good for America."(71) EPA administrator Carol Browner claimed that
"it is important to our efforts to diversify energy resources and promote
energy independence."(72) Assistant Secretary of Energy Sue Tierney told a
congressional panel a few days before the decision was announced that "the
primary beneficiary will be ADM, since their ethanol profits would
increase."(73) Assistant EPA administrator Mary Nichols conceded at the
time that, as the Washington Post reported, "Ethanol use probably will not
reduce greenhouse gas emissions in the short term because the production of
corn requires substantial amounts of energy, some of which results in
greenhouse gas emissions."(74)
The EPA waiver for ethanol's use in gasoline was the equivalent of allowing
city trash trucks to drop as much trash on the streets as they pick up from the
curbsides--and to double bill their customers. The federal government had gone
from ignoring pollution to benefit big business to mandating pollution to
benefit one specific fat-cat corporation.
The ethanol and farm lobbies' rolling of the Clinton administration on this
issue sparked a fierce backlash from environmental groups and other Washington
organizations. Fred Craft of the Oxygenated Fuel Association declared,
"This is the biggest gasoline change in the history of America. What the
hell is all this about? It has to do with market share. Ethanol interests don't
want the risks of the marketplace influencing their profits."(75) As the
National Journal noted, "Environmental activists cite a recent Energy
Department study suggesting that the EPA rule could lead to a slight increase
in pollution because of ethanol's volatility. And some state environmental
officials testified at congressional hearings last spring that the mandate
could worsen air quality and contribute to an increase in greenhouse gas
emissions."(76)
The Clinton administration's fuel-rule rigging provoked an
angry backlash from both liberal and conservative newspapers:
Forty-eight senators sent a letter of complaint to EPA administrator Carol
Browner. "This rule will create chaos in the marketplace, cause serious
RFG [reformulated gasoline] deliverability problems, and unnecessarily increase
the cost of RFG to consumers. Lastly, and most importantly, the rule will
result in no clear environmental benefits. . . . The ethanol industry is
already one of the most subsidized industries in the world."(83)
ADM responded to criticism of its rule rigging with indignation. Howard
Buffett, an ADM vice president (who resigned in July after news of the FBI
antitrust investigation of ADM broke), declared, "It is always incredible
to me that people accuse dedicated public servants of making judgments based on
these contributions. This implies that every time you write a check to support
the political process, the individual accepting it puts that above his
credibility, his integrity, and his service to his constituents."(84)
After public controversy erupted over ethanol's adverse impacts, Sen. Tom
Harkin (D-Iowa) found a unique way to persuade his fellow senators of the
safety of ethanol. Harkin challenged supporters of methanol, a competing
product that is also mixed with gasoline, to drink a glass of methanol (wood
alcohol) if Harkin was willing to drink a glass of ethanol (grain alcohol).
Harkin proceeded to drink part of a glass of ethanol at a Senate hearing.(85)
At the same time, the ethanol lobby paid for advertisements warning Americans
that methanol was a deadly poison that each year worldwide killed several thousand
people who drank it by mistake. The ads did not mention that ethanol, after it
is mixed with gasoline, is also fatal to swig.
The EPA ethanol mandate totally ignored the realities of gasoline markets
and gasoline marketing in the United States. The problems with the mandate were
vividly related to a Senate committee by Steve Berlin, a senior vice president
with Citgo Petroleum Corporation who had been in charge of both building up and
dismantling Citgo's own gasohol division. Berlin testified,
Based upon our experience, CITGO
is convinced that EPA's proposed ethanol mandate has the potential for severe
supply and price repercussions in the marketplace. . . . The interference with
the operation of the nation's fuel distribution system that the mandate will
entail virtually guarantees higher prices for gasoline and other fuels, spot
shortages, and increased environmental degradation.
Ethanol has several undesirable
properties as a motor fuel component, including miscibility with water and the
ability to act as a solvent for petroleum residences. Because of these
properties, gasolines containing ethanol cannot be transported by the national
pipeline distribution system for gasoline.
Many of the market areas in which
ethanol will have to be blended are not presently equipped to conduct ethanol
blending. . . .
EPA's proposed mandate for
blending of ethanol in gasolines in the Northeast and Mid-Atlantic is likely to
result in higher prices, not only for gasolines, but also for the heating oil
consumed in those regions.
Alarmingly, one company controls
over 65 percent of the U.S. ethanol production capacity. With this proposal, I
find it incredible that the federal government will be subsidizing basically a
single large company with both tax incentives and a mandated market share
without even a scintilla of regulation or oversight of that company.
Let's hold the EPA to its often
stated criteria: Today's solutions to environmental problems must be
"Cleaner, Cheaper and Smarter." EPA's proposed ethanol mandate fails
miserably. Ethanol is no cleaner than non-renewable oxygenates; indeed, it
actually poses additional adverse air emission risks. Ethanol is more expensive
to RFG gasoline consumers as well as to all taxpayers; and crisis
implementation is unwarranted when, as here, no crisis exists other than that
which will be produced by the EPA itself. In short, this mandate is
"Dirtier, Costlier, and Dumber."(86)
A federal appeals court agreed in a ruling on April 28: "The sole
purpose of the RFG program is to reduce air pollution, which it does through
specific performance standards for reducing . . . toxic emissions. EPA admits
that the [ethanol rule] will not give additional emission reductions for VOCs
or toxics . . . and has even conceded that the use of ethanol might possibly
make air quality worse."(87) The court ruled that the Clinton
administration had no statutory authority to forcibly subsidize ethanol
producers in a law designed to clean up the air.
After the federal appeals court shot down the EPA ruling, some Republicans
rushed to denounce the Clinton administration for failing to more effectively
flood ethanol producers with subsidies. Sen. Charles Grassley (R-Iowa)
declared, "In essence, with its ethanol policy the Clinton administration
handed big oil another victory, broke a campaign promise to farmers and
delivered a severe economic blow to rural America."(88)
The Clinton administration is considering a plan to "counteract"
the federal court decision striking down the ethanol mandate with a new
proposal to squander tens of millions of tax dollars. The Clean Air Network
Online Today newsletter noted on May 18 of this year, "The USDA is
considering the possibility of selling U.S.-distilled ethanol under USDA
concessional sales or export credit programs, according to USDA Secretary
Glickman. Glickman said the move was part of the Clinton administration's
efforts to help reach 'equivalence' in ethanol use with amounts forecast before
a court ruling against EPA's Renewable Oxygenate Standard. . . . Glickman said the
USDA was examining the PL 480 confessional sales program . . . and export
credit guarantees as a possible avenue for ethanol sales."(89) Glickman's
comments imply that the Clinton administration believed it had a sacred duty to
squander a certain number of tax dollars in the name of ethanol.
Ethanol Trade Barriers and the Rule of Origin Manipulation
Although ethanol has long been portrayed as a godsend for our environment,
members of Congress have worked overtime to prevent foreign ethanol from
improving the quality of American air. In 1980 Andreas persuaded the Carter
administration to slap a prohibitive tariff on ethanol imports, primarily from
Brazil. The story of the origin of the 60 cent tariff on Brazilian ethanol
imports was aptly related by Michael Fumento in the National Review in 1987.
In 1980, despite the enormous
subsidies it was already getting, American gasohol was being undersold by
Brazilian gasohol. American gasohol producers lobbied for a tariff, but the
Justice Department, the Office of the Special Trade Representative, and the
Treasury Department objected on the grounds that a tariff would raise costs to
consumers, provoke retaliation from Brazil, and grant too much power to ADM. On
October 7, in the White House, Jimmy Carter hosted a small luncheon for
campaign contributors, including Dwayne Andreas. Former ADM lobbyist Joseph
Karth, who was at the meeting, told me that Andreas told Carter he would
announce plans for a big new grain-alcohol plant in Iowa if the Administration
would guarantee the plant's profitability by imposing the tariff. . . . In the
last weeks of the election campaign Carter overruled his advisers and ordered
Treasury Secretary G. William Miller to impose a tariff, by administrative
means if necessary. On October 31, ADM announced the new plant, but canceled
its plan after the election.(90)
Rep. Charles Vanik (D-Ohio) fought the tariff hike, noting in a memo to
fellow members of Congress that it "contributes to the monopoly control of
the major domestic producer (the Archer Daniels Midland Company)." While
some Carter administration officials claimed to be concerned about the adverse
impact of imports, a Treasury staff memo in November 1980 reported that
"Treasury has been unable to verify allegations of plant closing due to
imports."(91) Shortly after the tariff was put in place, former Democratic
National Committee chairman Robert Strauss joined ADM's board of directors.
The ethanol defenders were not satisfied with blocking Brazilian ethanol. In
1983 Congress enacted the Caribbean Basin Initiative, granting duty-free access
to many Caribbean products. The 1983 law declared that as long as at least 35
percent of a product's value originated in the Caribbean, the product qualified
as a Caribbean product. Encouraged by the CBI, several companies invested tens
of millions of dollars to establish plants in Jamaica and Costa Rica to convert
surplus European wine into ethanol. The Customs Service ruled in 1984 that
ethanol production added more than 35 percent of the value to the finished
product, thus qualifying the Caribbean-produced ethanol for duty-free entry
into the United States.(92)
The 35 percent rule stood until a congressional tax conference in early
1986. One member of Congress slipped in an amendment to the tax bill that
raised the local value- added requirement for Caribbean ethanol from 35 percent
to 70 percent, creating a different rule of origin for ethanol than for any
other Caribbean product. That clause was a death sentence for Caribbean ethanol
producers. The 70 percent requirement effectively mandated the use of local
agricultural products for ethanol feedstock, but there were almost no surplus
agricultural stocks in the Caribbean.
The new, prohibitory rule of origin was a surprise because Caribbean ethanol
shipments posed no threat to American competitors: shipments never exceeded 3
percent of the U.S. ethanol supply.(93) U.S. ethanol produces still wanted to
lock out foreigners. U.S. producers, led by ADM working through the Renewable
Fuels Association, engineered an early-morning rule change to strangle any
possible foreign competition in the crib, as Washington lawyer Jim Moody
observed.(94)
The 1986 amendment gave existing Caribbean ethanol producers until 1990 to
reach the 70 percent local value requirement. In 1989 Congress again changed
the rule of origin for Caribbean ethanol. The new rule decreed that there would
be no Caribbean feedstock requirement on the first 60 million gallons of
ethanol imports, a 30 percent local feedstock requirement on the next 35
million gallons, and a 50 percent local feedstock requirement on any additional
imports. That rule, which effectively prohibits a sharp increase in Caribbean
exports, makes the national origin of ethanol dependent simply on the number of
gallons of ethanol imported.(95)
In sum, one would be hard-pressed to find another industry as artificially
sustained as the ethanol industry. The economics of ethanol are such that, for
the industry to survive at all, massive trade protection, tax loopholes, contrived
mandates for use, and production subsidies are vitally necessary. Only by
spooking the public with bogey- men such as foreign oil sheiks, toxic air
pollution, and the threatened disappearance of the American farmer can
attention be deflected from the real costs of the ethanol house of cards that
consumes over a billion dollars annually.
Sugar: ADM's Sweet Deal
The second federal trough that feeds ADM is the controversial sugar program,
under which U.S. import quotas and price supports provide even more artificial
profit for ADM than does the ethanol boondoggle. Although ADM does not directly
produce sugar, Congress and the USDA have created a price umbrella under which
ADM's production of high-fructose corn syrup--a sugar syrup--has become
immensely profitable.
ADM got into corn fructose production very heavily around 1974, just as
sugar prices peaked on world markets. After ADM invested heavily to increase
its capacity to produce high-fructose corn syrup ninefold, sugar prices
plummeted from 65 cents to 8 cents per pound. Andreas told Business Week in
1976, "If it was a mistake, I'd say it was my mistake." Business Week
noted, "One industry source suggests that 'Dwayne looks at this as sort of
a waiting game, basing his unflappability on the predicted passage of a new
sugar bill.' Such a bill is expected to provide an 'umbrella'--that is, to put
supports under sugar at a level where high-fructose corn syrup will be at least
reasonably profitable. Andreas contributed heavily to the 1968 and 1972
campaigns of Humphrey, Jackson and Nixon. With both parties covered, ADM may
reasonably anticipate some legislative help."(96) That help came in the
form of a new sugar bill in 1981.
ADM is the driving force behind the sugar lobby in this year's battle over
the future of the sugar program. The American Sugar Alliance, heavily
bankrolled by ADM, has spent lavishly for full-page newspaper ads showing how
cheap sugar is in the United States. The ads show that sugar costs 39 cents a
pound less here than in any other major country, noting that Brazilians pay 47
cents a pound and Russians pay 65 cents a pound.
However, there was a minor glitch in the ads. The Brazilian and Russian
prices were based on kilograms--2.2 pounds--and thus were actually
significantly lower than the U.S. price. As Al Kamen noted in the Washington
Post, "The Russians pay about nine cents a pound less and the Brazilians
about 17 cents less than we do" for sugar. The Post further reported that
"Joseph Lockhard, a spokesman for the anti-quota Coalition to End Welfare
for Big Sugar, accused the sugar alliance of knowingly letting the ad run even
after the errors were pointed out."(97)
ADM and farm-state representatives loudly brag that the sugar program is a
"no net cost" program. Although the sugar program mugs Americans at
the grocery checkout, representatives carefully designed the program so that it
leaves almost no fingerprints on the federal budget. The federal government maintains
a quota system designed to keep out low-priced foreign sugar and create a
perpetual artificial scarcity of sugar in the United States, which is then
combined with federal price supports to help jack up sugar prices even higher.
The sugar program is a great inflationary success: sugar sold for 22 cents a
pound in the United States when the world sugar price was only 4.5 cents a
pound (world sugar prices are now about 10.5 cents a pound although domestic
prices are still 22 cents per pound). Each 1 cent increase in the price of
sugar adds between $250 million and $300 million to consumers' food bills. A
l988 Commerce Department study estimated that the sugar program was costing
American consumers more than $3 billion a year.(98) That works out to more than
$60 a year for a family of four.
Members of Congress defend the sugar program as protecting Americans against
sharply fluctuating international sugar prices. The sugar program, like other
American farm programs, provides a price floor but no price ceiling. Thus, USDA
prevents prices from falling but allows prices to rise as high as the moon;
price supports are always a "heads, farmers win; tails, taxpayers
lose" proposition. If "price spikes" have been eliminated, it is
only because domestic sugar prices have been permanently plateaued at the
"spiked" level that world markets see only rarely and briefly.
ADM's angle is therefore clear. As journalist John Barnes noted in a 1987
story for the New Republic,
Since ADM can manufacture corn
sweetener for between 9 and 12 cents a pound and sell it for between 18 and 19
cents a pound, they easily undercut the price of domestic refined sugar and
make a killing.
Coke buys sweetener from Dwayne
Andreas for around 18 cents, while peasants starve for lack of customers at six
cents. In 1979 the entire corn sweetener industry produced just 1.7 million
metric tons. Since the imposition of the sugar quota, industry production has
soared to 5.5 million metric tons, more than 80 percent of it accounted for by
ADM.(99)
While ADM's television ads hype the company's supposed passionate concern
for the world's environment, its sugar policy is bad news for alligators.
Current agricultural trade barriers have resulted in food being produced in
many areas that do not have a comparative advantage or natural climate for food
production, such as sugar production in the United States. As a result, the
farmers compensate for the lack of natural habitat by dousing the land with
chemicals to artificially stimulate food production. One of the clearest
examples of the harm of farm protectionism is the role of sugar producers in
poisoning the Everglades. Drainage activities by the U.S. Army Corps of
Engineers and others have effectively paved the way for the conversion of
hundreds of thousands of acres of sensitive land to sugar cane plantations.
Phosphorus from the fertilizer used by sugar growers has leached into the water
of the Everglades and has helped destroy the ecosystem of the entire
region.(100)
There is no reason why the United States must produce its own sugar cane.
Sugar is cheaper in Canada primarily because Canada has almost no sugar growers
and thus no trade restrictions or government support programs. Paying lavish
subsidies to produce sugar in Florida makes as much sense as creating a federal
subsidy program to grow bananas in Massachusetts. The only thing that could
make American sugar cane farmers competitive would be massive global warming.
Another casualty of the sugar program is the poor people of Third World
nations. Sugar imports have been cut by 80 percent since 1975, pulverizing the
economies of Central America and the Philippines. The State Department
estimates that reducing U.S. sugar imports costs friendly Third World
governments almost a billion dollars a year.
The sugar program is corporate welfare at its most overt. The General
Accounting Office estimated that 17 of the nation's largest sugar cane farmers
received more than half of all the benefits provided by the sugar cane
subsidies.(101) The GAO also estimated that the 28 largest Florida sugar cane
producers received almost 90 percent of all the federal benefits enjoyed by
Florida sugar producers.(102) The U.S. Department of Agriculture estimates that
there is a total of 13,000 sugar farmers in the United States.(103) Assuming an
average annual consumer cost of $3 billion a year, since 1980 the sugar program
has cost American consumers the equivalent of more than $3 million for each
American sugar producer.
To Russia with Love--and
Money
The third major federal trough that feeds ADM is the various federally
subsidized grain export programs. Thus, it should not be surprising to find
that Dwayne Andreas just happens to have a deep and abiding interest in
U.S.-Soviet affairs. In 1984 Andreas became the U.S. chairman of the U.S.-USSR
Trade and Economic Council.
ADM: Supermarket to the Soviets
Andreas has been the foremost U.S. advocate of extending billions of dollars
of credit to the Soviets (and now the Russians) to buy American farm products
(kindly shipped to the Soviets in large part by ADM). The GAO recently reported
that there is a high likelihood that taxpayers will lose billions of dollars
when the Russian government defaults on those loans. Also, the flood of U.S.
handouts may have actually postponed substantive reform in the Soviet Union and
the Russian republic, thereby betraying the real needs of the Russian people
(as opposed to the political needs of Mikhail Gorbachev).
Andreas has long plowed the field of subsidized grain sales to the Soviet
Union, yet his version of history is extremely misleading. In December 1990
Andreas bragged at a House Agriculture Committee hearing,
For many years, I have devoted
much effort to improving business relationships between the USSR and the USA. Now
is a time when it would be clearly in our own best political and economic
interest to help meet the real basic needs of the USSR. It should be noted that
in 1973, we provided $750 million of credit to the Soviets for grain. This was
utilized and repaid with interest. It was profitable for both sides.(104)
Andreas chose a most unfortunate example to use to show the benefits of
giving credits and subsidies to the Soviets. In 1972 the USDA paid the largest
export subsidies ($700 million) in history to the Soviets to help them corner a
quarter of the American wheat crop. As GAO noted, USDA was supposed to have a
reporting system for foreign crop purchases but totally failed to monitor the
amount of Soviet purchases and kept subsidizing exports even after the Soviets
had cornered the U.S. market. The Soviet wheat sale fiasco drove wheat prices
from $1.25 a bushel to $4.75 a bushel and signaled the onset of a decade of
world inflation. In 1973, when OPEC announced it would dramatically cut
production in order to quadruple the price of oil, OPEC spokesmen justified
their decision by pointing at soaring wheat prices.
Politicians and political appointees responded to Andreas's exhortations to
continue bankrolling the Soviets and, later, the Russians and other nations of
the former Soviet Union. The Agriculture Department extended $5 billion in
credits to the Soviet Union and to Russia, Ukraine, and other former Soviet
states between early 1991 and 1993. USDA credits to the Soviets had already
been a matter of fierce dispute during congressional deliberations on the 1990
five-year farm bill. At that time Congress enacted a provision requiring that
"the Commodity Credit Corporation shall not make credit guarantees
available in connection with sales of agricultural commodities to any country
that the Secretary determines cannot adequately service the debt associated
with such sale."(105)
GAO concluded this past February, "Most, if not all, of the [Soviet]
successor states are not creditworthy and all should be considered at least
high risk from a credit worthiness perspective. . . . Most of the states have
had severe debt burden and severe liquidity problems. . . . The states are also
high risk entities because of their difficult economic and political
situations. . . . GAO's analysis of historical and forecast data indicates that
all of the successor states, as a group, were severely indebted in 1992 and
projected to remain so through 1997." GAO went on to note that
"USDA's own evaluations indicated that these states were very risky in
terms of their own ability to repay [USDA loans]."(106)
In 1985 Robert Strauss, an ADM board member and former chairman of the
Democratic National Committee, commented, "Dwayne Andreas just owns
me."(107) Six years later, when Strauss became the U.S. ambassador to the
Soviet Union, he urged the continuation of U.S. agricultural export credits to
the Soviet Union long after it was undeniable that the country was bankrupt.
In December 1990 Andreas implored the House Agriculture Committee to grant
still more credits: "The Soviets are in no position to complete purchases
under the longer-term grains agreement unless we are competitive. Credit terms
are part of the price. . . . The reduction in Soviet buying of U.S. grains has
importantly reduced our grain prices and increased the expense of our farm
programs. . . . Time is of the essence; anxious farmers and hungry people are
asking for a decision."(108)
While Andreas hyped subsidized exports as a sure-fire method of spurring
agricultural reform, other experts reached opposite conclusions. The GAO, in a
sharply critical 1995 report on U.S. export subsidies, concluded,
The progress of agricultural
reform in the successor states might be hindered by the provision of export
credits guaranteed by the United States and other countries. Credit guarantees
allow the successor states to continue to import billions of dollars of foreign
grain and other food commodities. Because these commodities are generally
purchased, processed, and distributed by state- owned enterprises, these
structures are likely to survive longer as state monopolies than might
otherwise be the case, although we were unable to quantify this effect. It is
these inefficient state enterprises that successor state reformers seek to
privatize or replace with alternative, nonstate structures, such as commodity
exchanges and private food processors, distributors and wholesalers. In
addition, credit-guarantee-assisted food imports might hinder domestic food
production and the efficient processing and marketing of this food by keeping
down prices offered to successor state farmers and food processors and
distributors.(109)
The USDA refuses to disclose the amount of ADM exports to the Soviet Union and
Russia that might have been covered by U.S. government credit guarantees on
which those countries later defaulted. Sally Nunn, an assistant treasurer in
the USDA's Commodity Credit Corporation, in response to a request for
disclosure of the amount of ADM exports involved in the credit defaults,
explained, "I have to have Secretary clearance [i.e., personal clearance
from Secretary of Agriculture Dan Glickman] to give out any information on
Russia."(110)
Attorney for the Defense
While Andreas was a high-profile supporter of aiding the Soviets, he was
something less than a champion of reform. As a 1991 New Republic editorial
noted a few days after the unsuccessful military coup, "Before the coup,
ADM and Pepsi had a marked preference for making their deals with Mr. Gorbachev
and ignoring the democratic forces led by Mr. Yeltsin."(111)
The day after the coup collapsed, Andreas rushed to declare that additional
U.S. food aid "would hasten reform" and that the failure of the coup
"will change the whole political climate of the West. Political resistance
against doing business with them [the Soviets] will disappear. This coup has
been a cloud over Gorbachev's head for a year, and every businessman and
politician has known it. Now it has evaporated."(112)
A few days after the coup attempt, Andreas told a CNN audience, "I
believe that the Republicans will now support him [Gorbachev] and that he
undoubtedly will run for reelection, and I will predict that Yeltsin and
Nazarbayev and the other important people will support him and he'll probably
be there for a long time to come."(113)
In an August 27, 1991, speech, Andreas declared, "Now, any help they
get will help the move to democracy and free markets. We can help them by
inundating them with food."(114) Andreas had apparently changed his mind
about the negative economics of imports since the time he sought to prevent
foreign countries such as Brazil from "inundating" the U.S. market
with ethanol.
In mid-September 1991 Andreas told the International Herald Tribune that
without food aid, "the hard-liners, with their dog-in-the-manger attitude,
will be able to use this anger to stir up trouble. This could lead to anarchy,
even a climate that would permit another coup."(115)
On September 9, 1991, Andreas told the House Armed Services Committee,
"By far, the most important threat to Soviet stability today is the food
problem. Soviet leaders tell me, and I believe them, that they must quickly
make large quantities of food conspicuously visible on the shelves of stores in
their eight largest cities to stabilize prices and discourage
hoarding."(116)
Andreas denounced the U.S. hesitation to approve more credits in October
1991 by challenging the authority of Congress to even have a say in his
executive deal making: "The fact that the President had to go for an act
of Congress is just a black mark on America's reputation as a trading nation. .
. . The Cold War was very cold. It takes a long time for it to thaw. You still
have in our government little isolated groups of cold warriors who sabotage
anything the president is trying to do."(117)
Although Andreas had previously bragged about the successes of Soviet
reforms, after the coup he changed his tune and began cozying up to the new
bosses in Russia. Food Engineering magazine reported in October 1991 that
Andreas said after the coup, "The outlook is better than ever before
because the democratic forces are in charge. Before the coup, the communists
were sabotaging reform."(118)
Still, Andreas continued to blame Gorbachev's failure on the narrow-minded
and "useless" people in Washington who refused to give the Soviets
[and thus ADM] even more than the billions that Gorbachev received. It was,
apparently, our fault that the communist remnant was sabotaging reform. Said Andreas
in January 1992, "If the West had taken a chance three years ago and
allowed the Soviet Union to join the IMF and the World Bank, the communists
might have changed. With that western team helping them the communists could
have taken tough decisions--like making the ruble convertible. But the western
economists failed to grasp what was going on. They were useless. Taking a
chance with Gorbachev was low priority in Washington."(119)
Yet, while Andreas was on the hustings urging the U.S. government to provide
as many financial credits as possible to underwrite ADM's and other companies'
sales to the Soviets, he was reticent when asked about the use of his own
money. In January 1992 an interviewer asked him directly, "Would you
invest in whatever the Soviet Union is called now?" Andreas replied,
"The whole country is one big train wreck."(120) While Andreas was
urging the U.S. government to throw more billions down the rat hole, ADM was
working to make sure that it got hard value for its exports--offering to
exchange its grain for Soviet-built cargo ships.(121)
Some of Andreas's comments about Gorbachev display a level of credulity that
would embarrass a six year old, if not a Central Intelligence Agency
sovietologist. For example, Andreas sought to explain away some of the Soviet
Union's economic problems, declaring in August 1991 that "Gorbachev and
his emissaries have been saying quite recently, and in recent months, that
they're experiencing a very strange phenomenon in the Soviet Union, which is
hoarding."(122) Hoarding has been a predominant phenomenon in the Soviet
Union since the days of the Bolshevik Revolution. A trademark of the Soviet
economy has been pervasive shortages, and the natural response to the shortages
is hoarding.
Export Subsidies: ADM's "Golden Package"
Since 1985 ADM has received more than $130 million in Export Enhancement
Program subsidy bonuses to boost its exports (the export enhancement program
bonuses from USDA are not as direct a subsidy as many other programs; the
corporate recipients use the subsidies in part to help lower the net prices to
foreign buyers). ADM has also significantly benefited from credits that the
USDA has extended to foreign nations to buy exports from American companies,
and taxpayers have gotten burned badly by defaults on those credits. Long a
central staple of corporate welfare masquerading as humanitarian farm policy,
export subsidies not only rob the taxpayer but do positive harm to the third-
party recipients of congressional generosity.
The case for such programs was made quite directly by Andreas in a hearing
before the Senate Agricultural Committee on May 25. But in one of the great
unnoticed novelties of this year, a politician for once had the courage to
publicly challenge Andreas's sleight-of-hand economics and lay bare the ruse
behind the export subsidy program.
Andreas testified that day on behalf of the Coalition to Promote U.S.
Agriculture Exports--that is, the committee to continue federal bankrolling of
dumping U.S. crops on world markets. Andreas's written testimony had some gems
of logic, including this revelation based on his decades of experience in
international trade: "Without exports, America's trade deficit would be
even worse." Andreas also observed,
I am here today . . . to call for
action to meet the challenge of today's post-GATT global marketplace. . . . In
the context of debate on the budget and the 1995 Farm Bill, we hear it said
that now is the time to sharply reduce or even eliminate many of our existing
policies and programs and simply allow the free market to work. Well, let me
tell you, when it comes to agriculture--there is no such thing as the free
market. . . .
The global marketplace is still
characterized by heavily subsidized foreign competition. This is because GATT
did not eliminate the use of export subsidies or other unfair trade practices.
It only reduced their overall level. As a result, it has served to legitimize
their continued use.
We cannot and should not expect
American agriculture to compete alone against foreign government.
We should maintain funding and
aggressively implement the full range of policies and programs available to us
as allowed under GATT and U.S. law.
This includes direct export
programs such as EEP as well as the Dairy Export Incentive Program (DEIP), and
Cottonseed and Sunflower Oil Assistance Programs (COAP and SOAP).(123)
Andreas fielded a few softball questions from Sen. Jesse Helms (R-N.C.), who
asked what ADM would do if Congress abolished the export subsidies. Andreas
responded, "If you do away with those export subsidies like EEP, you will
immediately have huge storage charges built up on grains that stay in our bins.
My company stores 400 million bushels of grain. It would be a bonanza for us if
you stopped the exports because our elevators would fill up. Storing grain for
the government is very profitable. I do not think you can afford to do away
with those export programs because the cost of the farm program will rise
precipitously if you do that." But if Congress abolished farm policies that
sabotage U.S. farm exports at the same time that it abolished export subsidies,
no grain pileup would occur.
The most insightful exchange of the hearing took place between Sen. Rick
Santorum (R-Penn.) and Andreas:
Santorum: Do your affiliates in
the European Union testify in support of their export subsidies?
Andreas: My partners in the EU
are 12 of the biggest farmers' cooperatives in the world, and they have, of
course, their own philosophy and their own scheme of things. . . . The
agricultural commodity business is so competitive that if we withdrew our
export subsidies for two months, grain would back up all over this country and
the government would have to pay to store it and the cost would rise. I am just
stating facts.
Santorum: There is some
information from the CRS in 1991 that said that 70 to 90 percent of all wheat
sales that were subsidized by the EEP would have been sold anyway. . . .
Andreas: I certainly disagree.
That just is not true. That is just a ridiculous statement. Who made that
statement?
Santorum: The Congressional
Research Service.
Andreas: It is ridiculous.(124)
Next, the conversation turned to the question of existing U.S. subsidies for
exports of durum wheat to Italy and Turkey. Italian and Turkish manufacturers have
taken the fire-sale wheat, made it into pasta, and exported that pasta back to
the United States. Senator Santorum asked Andreas how the U.S. government
should respond in a case like that. Andreas answered, "If we find that we
need to subsidize the export to compete abroad, we could subsidize the pasta
exports just as well as the wheat exports."(125)
Andreas, of course, must come out stridently in favor of export subsidies
and control by politicians of exports or else the harm of political control of
domestic markets would become too stark. After all, much of Andreas's success
comes from his audience. Politicians are almost never paying for any of the
programs with their own money, and as long as a program or policy creates some
nice photo opportunities (pictures of P.L. 480 grain exports) or some nice
rhetoric, it is a profitable program for politicians. Andreas is very
successful with politicians because many politicians do not care about
taxpayers' and consumers' profits and losses.
"Food for Peace" or "Food for Profit"?
ADM has long been a major beneficiary of the Food for Peace program through
which surplus U.S. agricultural products are dumped on foreign nations. In 1978
ADM pleaded "no contest" to charges of price fixing and paid $200,000
in criminal penalties in connection with the sale of grain to the Food for
Peace program.(126) Even though Andreas continues to champion foreign food aid
programs, the harm of those programs has long been obvious.(127) In the 1950s
and 1960s massive U.S. wheat dumping in India disrupted India's agricultural
market and helped bankrupt thousands of Indian farmers.(128) In 1984 George
Dunlop, chief of staff of the Senate Agriculture Committee, speculated that
American food aid might have been responsible for the starvation of millions of
Indians.(129) U.S. officials have conceded that massive food aid to Indonesia,
Pakistan, and India in the 1960s "restricted agricultural growth . . . by
allowing the governments to (1) postpone essential agricultural reforms, (2)
fail to give agricultural investment sufficient priority, and (3) maintain a
pricing system which gave farmers an inadequate incentive to increase
production."(130)
Other nations have been similarly hammered by subsidized U.S. exports.
No matter how sanctimoniously Andreas attempts to wrap his subsidies in
humanitarian garb, the evidence that those programs actually help the intended
recipients is scarce indeed. The clearest beneficiary, once again, is ADM.
America's Costs vs. ADM's
Profits
Prudential Securities analyst John McMillin estimated that ADM's $746
million in profits in fiscal year 1995 (ending June 30) was derived as follows:
At least 43 percent of ADM's annual profits are from products heavily
subsidized or protected by the U.S. government--"at least," because
the substantial gain derived by ADM from various domestic crop support programs
and export subsidies is virtually impossible to quantify.
ADM's lobbying and campaign contributions may have saved the federal sugar
program from being abolished by Congress. Because the current sugar trade
barriers and price supports cost consumers roughly $3 billion a year, consumers
paid $10 in higher prices for each dollar of profit that ADM reaped from corn
sweeteners.
ADM's lobbying and campaign contributions have certainly been the key force
in creating and perpetuating federal ethanol subsidies. Because combined
federal and state ethanol subsidies probably amount to more than $1 billion,
every dollar of ADM ethanol profits is costing the American public more than
$30.
ADM's finagling in Washington may have cost taxpayers and consumers more
than $40 billion since 1980, counting the cost of the sugar program ($3 billion
in higher prices each year), the ethanol program, and federal food giveaways
and export subsidies. Some of those dubious programs probably would have been
enacted even if Andreas had not been foisting cash on every politician in
sight, but ADM deserves credit for being a decisive force in enacting and
perpetuating many of the federal government's most abusive policies.
ADM's political strategy has long been based on the ideas that politicians
should control prices and markets and that ADM and Andreas should control
politicians. Some commentators may conclude that the ADM experience proves the
need for campaign finance reform, but that would be the triumph of hope over
experience. Campaign finance laws have been repeatedly revised in recent
decades, yet politics does not smell any better.(137) As long as the
politicians are shoveling out billions of dollars in handouts, some citizens
will find a way to reward politicians for "looking after their
interests."
Besides, at a time when Congress is rightfully moving toward removing
millions of able-bodied citizens from welfare rolls, there is no excuse to
perpetuate handouts for a company like ADM. If a company can afford endless
advertisements on national television, it is safe to conclude that it does not
need any help from American taxpayers.
The Supreme Court, in Savings and Loan Association v. Topeka (1875), stated,
"To lay with one hand the power of the government on the property of the
citizen and with the other to bestow it upon favored individuals to aid private
enterprises and build up private fortunes is none the less a robbery because it
is done under the forms of law and is called taxation."(138) Andreas
apparently can buy politicians, but that does not mean that ADM has a right to
shake down American consumers and taxpayers.
Congress, in the pending farm bill and in legislation to extend the ethanol
gasoline fuel tax credit, has an excellent chance to shut down the ADM gravy
train. Congress's action on the ADM agenda will be an appropriate litmus test
of the new Republican leadership's spine. If Congress cannot stand up to ADM,
how can they be expected to stand up for American taxpayers and consumers in
other, less egregious cases?
Notes
(1) See, generally, Stephen Moore and Dean Stansel, "Ending Corporate
Welfare As We Know It," Policy Analysis no. 225, Cato Institute, May 12,
1995.
(2) Quoted in Dan Carney, "Dwayne's World," Mother Jones,
July-August 1995, p. 47.
(3) Quoted in Michael Isikoff, "Andreas: College Drop-Out to Global
Trader," Washington Post, December 8, 1985.
(4) Quoted in Michael Weiss, "The High Octane Ethanol Lobby," New
York Times, April 1, 1990.
(5) Jill Abramson and Phil Kuntz, "Antitrust Probe of Archer Daniels
Puts Spotlight on Chairman Andreas's Vast Political Influence," Wall
Street Journal, July 11, 1995.
(6) Isikoff, "Andreas."
(7) Weiss.
(8) Abramson and Kuntz.
(9) Weiss.
(10) "Companies Flew Dole 187 Times," Charleston Daily Mail, April
17, 1995.
(11) Abramson and Kuntz.
(12) Timothy Noah, "Ethanol Boon Shows How Archer Daniels Gets Its Way
in Washington with Low-Key Lobbying," Wall Street Journal, December 29,
1993.
(13) Ibid.
(14) Frank Greven, "He Gives, He Gets--You Pay," Charlotte
Observer, January 23, 1995.
(15) Ibid.
(16) "This Clean Air Looks Dirty," editorial, New York Times, July
8, 1994.
(17) Peter Stone, "The Big Harvest," National Journal, July 30,
1994, p. 1790.
(18) Greven.
(19) Michael Fumento, "Some Dare Call Them Robber Barons,"
National Review, March 13, 1987, p. 32.
(20) Carney.
(21) Anna Cekola, "Agribusiness Executive Donates $1 Million to Nixon
Think Tank," Los Angeles Times, June 6, 1994.
(22) Isikoff, "Andreas."
(23) Jerry Knight, "Gartner Clings to Trading Commission Post,"
Washington Post, June 28, 1978.
(24) Weiss.
(25) "They're Interested," editorial, Wall Street Journal, March
30, 1993.
(26) Quoted in "Taxes Need to Cut U.S. Budget Deficit--ADM Head,"
Reuters, January 26, 1993.
(27) Charles Siler, "Weatherman," Forbes, February 22, 1988, p.
40.
(28) Quoted in David Greising, "Big Stink on the Farm," Business
Week, July 20, 1992.
(29) Thomas Donlan, "Whiskey Rebellion," Barron's, May 23, 1994.
(30) Abramson and Kuntz.
(31) Salvatore Lazzari, "Alcohol Fuels Tax Incentives and EPA's
Renewable Oxygenate Requirement," Congressional Research Service, October
7, 1994.
(32) 21st Century Fuels, August 1995.
(33) J. P. Smith, "Gasohol Advocates Lobbying Intensively,"
Washington Post, April 23, 1979.
(34) The $23 figure is from Lazzari.
(35) Office of Energy, "Fuel Ethanol and Agriculture: An Economic
Assessment," U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Economic Report
no. 562, August 1986, p. 4.
(36) Ibid.
(37) Lazzari.
(38) Office of Energy, p. 3.
(39) Greven.
(40) Jane Bryant Quinn, "Gasohol: Is the Cure Worse Than the
Malady?" Washington Post, February 18, 1980.
(41) "Gasohol Loan Guarantees Announced," Associated Press,
October 10, 1980.
(42) William Kronholm, "Agency Improperly Approved Millions in Loan
Guarantees, Probers Say," Associated Press, February 7, 1981.
(43) Quoted in Ronald Henkoff, "Oh, How the Money Grows at ADM,"
Fortune, October 8, 1990.
(44) Michael Isikoff, "USDA Starts Major Gasohol Subsidy Plan,"
Washington Post, June 3, 1986.
(45) Ibid.
(46) Quoted in Jonathan Adler, "Alternative Fuel Follies with Ethanol
Vapors," Washington Times, May 3, 1995.
(47) Interview with Hosein Shapouri, September 5, 1995.
(48) "A Binbuster Corn Crop," Cargill Bulletin, March 1995.
(49) Office of Energy, pp. iv-v.
(50) Ibid., p. 38. Emphasis added.
(51) "Agriculture Dept. New Crop Estimates," Journal of Commerce,
November 10, 1994, p. 8.
(52) Mark Peters, "The Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990 and
Agriculture," Feed Situation and Outlook, U.S. Department of Agriculture,
November 1993, p. 27.
(53) Ibid.
(54) Interview with Fred Sanderson, July 21, 1986.
(55) Office of Energy, p. vi.
(56) Bureau of National Affairs, "Special Supplement," March 6,
1995, p. S-62, citing Congressional Budget Office, "Reducing the Deficit:
Spending and Revenue Options," March 3, 1995.
(57) Greg Clock, "Gasohol: Is It a Plus or Minus in the U.S.?" Oil
& Gas Journal, March 3, 1980.
(58) Gary Lee, "Behind Fuel Additive Decision, a Debate over Corn or
Natural Gas," Washington Post, August 8, 1994.
(59) Larry Kramer, "EPA Will Allow Continued Sale of Fuel
'Gasohol,'" Washington Post, December 16, 1978.
(60) Ibid.
(61) Office of Energy, p. 43.
(62) Rick Henderson, "Dirty Driving: Donald Stedman and the EPA's Sins
of Emission," Policy Review, April 1992, p. 56.
(63) Cited in Alston Chase, "Tillers of Ecological Correct ness,"
Washington Times, July 31, 1994.
(64) Congressional Budget Office, "Reducing the Deficit: Spending and
Revenue Options," March 3, 1995.
(65) Lazzari.
(66) Anne Hazard, "EPA Administrator Mum on Whether Negative Findings
Will Cause Ethanol Rule to be Withdrawn," States News Service, May 13,
1994.
(67) David Greising, "Big Stink on the Farm," Business Week, July
20, 1992.
(68) "Remarks of President George Bush, Ethanol Announcement,"
Federal News Service, October 1, 1992.
(69) Earl Anderson, "Ethanol's Role in Reformulated Gasoline Stirs
Controversy," Chemical & Engineering News, November 2, 1992, p. 7.
(70) Ibid.
(71) Stone.
(72) "EPA to Require Cleaner-Burning Gas in Polluted Areas," New
York Times, July 1, 1994.
(73) Gary Lee, "EPA Backs Ethanol for Fuel," Washington Post, July
1, 1994.
(74) Ibid.
(75) Stone.
(76) Ibid.
(77) "This Clean Air Looks Dirty."
(78) "Corn for Community," editorial, Washington Post, July 4,
1994.
(79) "Another Idiocy from EPA," editorial, Boston Herald, April 4,
1994.
(80) "Rough as a Cob," editorial, Houston Post, July 5, 1994.
(81) "Don't Mandate Ethanol for Clean Air Effort," editorial, USA
Today, June 10, 1994.
(82) "Why Ethanol?" editorial, Houston Chronicle, March 28, 1994.
(83) "48 Senators Urge EPA to Drop Ethanol Plan," BNA National
Environmental Daily, March 7, 1994.
(84) Nelson Schwartz, "Does Agriculture Giant Reap Politicians?"
Baltimore Sun, July 9, 1994.
(85) "Ethanol Beats Methanol and MTBE in Sen. Harkin's Cocktail
Challenge," Clean Air Network Online Today, June 9, 1994.
(86) Steve Berlin, senior vice president, Citgo Petroleum Corporation,
"Proposed Market Mandates for Ethanol," Testimony before the Senate
Energy and Natural Resources Committee, May 12, 1994, Federal Document Clearing
House.
(87) Adler.
(88) Jake Thompson, "Ethanol for Campaigns as Well as Cars,"
Kansas City Star, May 7, 1995.
(89) "USDA Considering Ethanol Sales Abroad to Reach Usage
'Equivalence,'" Clean Air Network Online Today, May 18, 1995.
(90) Fumento.
(91) Clyde Farnsworth, "Washington Watch: Farm Lobby's Gasohol
Victory," New York Times, December 1, 1980.
(92) U.S. Congress, House Ways and Means Committee, Fuel Ethanol Imports
from Caribbean Basin Initiative Countries, April 25, 1989 (Washington:
Government Printing Office, 1989), p. 80.
(93) Ibid., p. 36.
(94) Interview with Jim Moody, September 1, 1995.
(95) U.S. Congress, Customs and Trade Act of 1990, Conference Report 101650
(Washington: Government Printing Office, 1990), p. 136.
(96) "When Competition against Sugar Turned Sour," Business Week,
November 1, 1976.
(97) Al Kamen, "Spooning Out the Sugar Stats," Washington Post,
July 3, 1995.
(98) "Commerce Study Faults U.S. Sugar Program," International
Trade Reporter, May 25, 1988, p. 741.
(99) John Barnes, "Anatomy of a Rip-Off," New Republic, November
2, 1987, p. 21.
(100) Jonathan Tolman, "Federal Agricultural Policy: A Harvest of
Environmental Abuse," Competitive Enterprise Institute, Washington, August
1995.
(101) General Accounting Office, "Former Soviet Union: Creditworthiness
of Successor States and U.S. Export Credit Guarantees," February 1995, p.
31.
(102) Ibid.
(103) U.S. Department of Agriculture, "Government Support for the U.S.
Sugar Industry," Agriculture Information Bulletin no. 664-55, June 1993.
(104) "Andreas Strongly Advocates Extending Credits to USSR,"
Milling and Baking News, December 11, 1990.
(105) Sen. Patrick Leahy, "Criticism of Past Russian Aid," Press
release, March 24, 1995.
(106) "Ex-Soviets Too Risky for U.S. Food Credits--GAO," Reuters,
March 27, 1995.
(107) Isikoff, "Andreas."
(108) "Andreas Strongly Advocates Extending Credits to USSR."
(109) General Accounting Office, p. 47.
(110) Telephone interview with Sally Nunn, September 13, 1995.
(111) "Mission to Moscow," editorial, New Republic, September 16,
1991. The New Republic dates its issues several weeks after the actual
publication date; thus, this issue came out just after the coup.
(112) George Anthan, "Some Say U.S. Food Aid Would Help Soviet
Union," Gannett News Service, August 22, 1991.
(113) Interview with Lou Dobbs, Moneyline, CNN, August 26, 1991.
(114) "Archer Daniels Chief: Soviet Breakdown Good for Trade,"
UPI, August 27, 1991.
(115) Barry James, "The Soviet Union Needs Food, and Fast, an Expert
Declares," International Herald Tribune, September 16, 1991.
(116) "ADM Chairman Calls for Massive Food Assistance for Soviet
Union," Milling and Baking News, September 10, 1991.
(117) George Gunset, "ADM Chief: Get Down to Business with Soviet
Union," Chicago Tribune, October 6, 1991.
(118) Patricia Dillon, "It's Business as Usual," Food Engineering,
October 1991, p. 157.
(119) Sonddra Gotlieb, "Gorbachev's Misfortune," Financial Post,
January 10, 1992.
(120) Ibid.
(121) "U.S. Firm Offers to Barter Grains for Soviet Ships," Agra
Europe, May 4, 1990.
(122) Interview with Lou Dobbs.
(123) Dwayne Andreas, Statement for the Senate Agriculture Committee hearing
on "1995 Farm Bill: Export Programs," May 25, 1995.
(124) U.S. Senate Agriculture Committee, hearing on "1995 Farm Bill:
Export Programs," transcript, p. 55.
(125) Ibid.
(126) Isikoff, "Andreas."
(127) See Clifton B. Luttrell, The High Cost of Farm Welfare (Washington:
Cato Institute, 1989), pp. 43-53.
(128) James Bovard, "Free Food Bankrupts Foreign Farmers," Wall
Street Journal, July 2, 1984.
(129) Ibid.
(130) Ibid.
(131) Ibid.
(132) Ibid.
(133) U.S. Agency for International Development, "Audit of the P.L. 480
Title I Program in Somalia," January 26, 1987, p. 10.
(134) Interview with former AID official, June 7, 1988.
(135) Bovard.
(136) Don Boroughs, "Reaping a Bitter Harvest," U.S. News &
World Report, July 24, 1995, p. 39.
(137) Bradley Smith, "Campaign Finance Regulation: Faulty Assumptions
and Undemocratic Consequences," Cato Institute Policy Analysis no. 239,
September 13, 1995.
(138) Savings and Loan Association v. Topeka, 20 Wall. 655, (1875).
©
1995 The Cato Institute
Please send comments to webmaster